1 / 57

Econ 522 Economics of Law

Econ 522 Economics of Law. Dan Quint Spring 2011 Lecture 16. Last week…. Elements of a tort Harm ; causation ; breach of duty (negligence) Strict liability rule: no need to prove negligence, just harm and causation Negligence rule: need to prove all three elements

xiang
Download Presentation

Econ 522 Economics of Law

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Econ 522Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2011 Lecture 16

  2. Last week… • Elements of a tort • Harm; causation; breach of duty (negligence) • Strict liability rule: no need to prove negligence, just harm and causation • Negligence rule: need to prove all three elements • Precaution: any actions taken to reduce likelihood of an accident • Began to set up simple model to evaluate liability rules

  3. x level of precautionw marginal cost of precautionp(x) probability of an accidentA cost of an accident Model of unilateral harm $ wx + p(x) A(Total Social Cost) x < x* x > x* wx (Cost of Precaution) p(x) A (Cost of Accidents) Precaution (x) x* (Efficient Level of Precaution)

  4. Effect of Liability Ruleson Precaution

  5. Effect of liability rules on precaution • Three rules we’ll consider: • No liability • Strict liability • Negligence

  6. Rule 1: No Liability • Injurer’s private costis just wx • Minimized at x = 0 • Victim’s private costis p(x) A + wx • Minimized at efficientprecaution level x = x* • So rule of no liability leads to efficient precaution by victims, no precaution by injurers $ Private cost to injurer Private cost to victim wx + p(x) A wx p(x) A x x*

  7. Rule 2: Strict Liability • Perfect compensation(Damages = A) • Injurer’s private costis p(x) A + wx • Minimized at efficientprecaution level x = x* • Victim’s private costis just wx • Minimized at x = 0 • So rule of strict liability leads to efficient precaution by injurers, no precaution by victims $ Private cost to injurer Private cost to victim wx + p(x) A wx p(x) A x x*

  8. Effect of liability rules on precaution Victimprecaution Injurerprecaution No Liability Efficient Zero Strict Liability Zero Efficient

  9. So for accidents with unilateral precaution… • When it’s the injurer who can take precautions, a rule of strict liability is more efficient • When it’s the victim who can take precautions, a rule of no liability is more efficient • Each rule works well for one incentive, poorly for other • Similar to paradox of compensation we saw in contract law • Negligence rule may allow us to get both incentives right

  10. Rule 3: “Simple Negligence” • Legal standard of care xn • Injurer is liable for damages if precaution level was below the legal standard of care • x < xn D = A • x ³ xn  D = 0 • So on our graph from before, private cost to injurer is… • wx + p(x) A for x < xn • wx for x ³ xn • Since we’re shooting for efficiency, we’ll suppose xn = x*

  11. Rule 3: Simple NegligenceInjurer precaution $ Private cost to injurer wx + p(x) A wx p(x) A x xn = x* • Private cost is wx + p(x) A if x < xn, only wx otherwise • If standard of care is set efficiently (xn = x*), injurer minimizes private cost by taking efficient precaution

  12. Rule 3: Simple NegligenceVictim precaution • What about victim? • We just said, injurer will take efficient precaution • Which means injurer will not be liable • So victim bears costs of any accidents • (Victim bears residual risk) • So victim’s private cost is wx + p(x) A • Victim minimizes private cost by taking efficient level of precaution too! $ Private cost to victim (assuming injurer takes efficient level of precaution and is therefore not liable for damages) wx + p(x) A wx p(x) A x*

  13. Effect of liability rules on precaution Victimprecaution Injurerprecaution No Liability Efficient Zero Strict Liability Zero Efficient Simple Negligence,with xn = x* Efficient Efficient

  14. In fact, there are several ways we could implement a negligence rule • Rule we just saw: injurer is liable if he was negligent, not liable if he wasn’t • “Simple Negligence” • Doesn’t consider whether victim was negligent, only injurer • But we can consider both whether injurer was negligent, and whether victim was negligent, in determining liability • “Negligence with a defense of contributory negligence” – injurer owes nothing if victim was also negligent • “Comparative negligence” – if both were negligent, share cost • “Strict liability with defense of contributory negligence” – injurer is liable unless victim was negligent

  15. The cool part… • When standards of care for both injurer and victim are set to the efficient level… • …any of these negligence rules leads to efficient level of precaution by both parties • Already saw this works for simple negligence • Could show the others the same way • Instead, we’ll do a discrete example

  16. Discrete example ofbilateral precaution A $1,000w $20 for either partyp 10% / 6% / 2% • No “levels” of precaution – each party can either take precaution or not • Each accident causes $1,000 of harm • Precaution costs $20 for each party • Chance of an accident is • 10% if nobody takes precaution • 6% if one party takes precaution • 2% if both parties take precaution • Note that precaution is efficient for both parties • Costs $20; reduces expected accidents by 4% X $1,000 = $40

  17. Different negligence rules A $1,000w $20 for either partyp 10% / 6% / 2% Does injurer owe victim damages when… Neither party negligent? Only victim negligent? Only injurer negligent? Both parties negligent? Simple Negligence No No Yes Yes Negligence with Defense of Contributory Negligence No No Yes No

  18. Negligence with a Defenseof Contributory Negligence A $1,000w $20 for either partyp 10% / 6% / 2% • Injurer is liable if he failed to take precaution… • Unless victim did too • Precaution is a dominantstrategy for victim • If injurer is not takingprecaution, victim wantsto avoid liability • If injurer is takingprecaution, victim bearsresidual risk, wants tominimize accidents • For injurer, precaution is the best-response to precaution • “Both take precaution” is the only Nash equilibrium • And, is the efficient outcome victim pays for precaution, and any accidents that happen injurer pays for precaution, not liable for accidents Victim Precaution None -20, -40 -20, -60 Precaution Injurer -60, -20 0, -100 None 17

  19. Different negligence rules A $1,000w $20 for either partyp 10% / 6% / 2% Does injurer owe victim damages when… Neither party negligent? Only victim negligent? Only injurer negligent? Both parties negligent? Simple Negligence No No Yes Yes Negligence with Defense of Contributory Negligence No No Yes No Comparative Negligence No No Yes Partial

  20. Comparative Negligence A $1,000w $20 for either partyp 10% / 6% / 2% • If both parties were negligent… • …divide cost proportionally • Precaution is again adominant strategy forvictim • Now it’s a dominant strategyfor injurer too • Again, “both take precaution” is the only equilibrium • (And the efficient outcome) Victim Precaution None -20, -40 -20, -60 Precaution Injurer -60, -20 -50, -50 None 19

  21. Different negligence rules A $1,000w $20 for either partyp 10% / 6% / 2% Does injurer owe victim damages when… Neither party negligent? Only victim negligent? Only injurer negligent? Both parties negligent? Simple Negligence No No Yes Yes Negligence with Defense of Contributory Negligence No No Yes No Comparative Negligence No No Yes Partial Strict Liability with Defense of Contributory Negligence Yes No Yes No

  22. Strict Liability with a Defenseof Contributory Negligence A $1,000w $20 for either partyp 10% / 6% / 2% • Now, injurer is liable,regardless of whetherhe took precaution… • …unless victimwas negligent • Once again, “bothtake precaution” isthe only equilibrium Victim Precaution None -40, -20 -20, -60 Precaution Injurer -60, -20 0, -100 None 21

  23. So with bilateral precaution… Victimprecaution Injurerprecaution No Liability Efficient Zero Strict Liability Zero Efficient Simple negligence Efficient Efficient Negligence with Defense of Contributory Negligence Efficient Efficient assuming standards of care are set equal to efficient levels Comparative negligence Efficient Efficient Strict Liability with Defense of Contributory Negligence Efficient Efficient

  24. (Aside: with bilateral precaution, things occasionally get more complicated…) • Redundant precaution – either party could take precaution, efficiency only requires one of them • If precaution is continuous, any negligence rule still leads to efficient precaution level by both • When precaution is discontinuous, not always • Driver can fasten seatbelt, or car company can design seatbelt that buckles itself (more costly) • Simple negligence: car company might be liable if designed manual seatbelt and driver didn’t use it, so car company might design automatic belt • Negligence with defense of contributory negligence: car company escapes liability, so designs manual belt, rational driver uses it • But as long as precaution is continuous, no problem

  25. So far, our results seem to favor negligence rules… but… Victimprecaution Injurerprecaution No Liability Efficient Zero Strict Liability Zero Efficient Efficient Efficient Any negligence rule with efficient legal standards of care • Next twist: activity levels

  26. Activity Levels

  27. Activity levels • Precaution – actions which make an activity less dangerous • Driving carefully • Wearing bright-colored clothing while bicycling • The amount we do each activity also affects the number of accidents • I decide how much to drive • You decide how much to bicycle • Liability rules create incentives for activity levels as well as precaution

  28. Activity levels under a rule of no liability • With no liability, I’m not responsible if I hit you • I don’t consider cost of accidents when deciding how fast to drive… • …or when deciding how much to drive • So I drive too recklessly, and I drive too much • With no liability, you bear full cost of accidents • You maximize benefit of activity, minus cost of precaution, minus cost of accidents • You take efficient level of precaution, and efficient level of activity • A rule of no liability leads to an inefficiently high level of injurer activity, but the efficient level of victim activity

  29. Adding activity levels to our results on precaution… Injurer Precaution Victim Precaution Injurer Activity Victim Activity No Liability Zero Efficient Too High Efficient Strict Liability Efficient Zero Simple Negligence Efficient Efficient Negligence with a Defense of Contributory Negligence Efficient Efficient Comparative Negligence Efficient Efficient Strict Liability with Defense of Contributory Negligence Efficient Efficient

  30. Activity levels under a rule of strict liability • Under strict liability, injurer internalizes cost of accidents • Weighs benefit from driving against cost of accidents • Takes efficient activity level • Under strict liability, victim does not bear cost of accidents • Ignores cost of accidents when deciding how much to bike • Sets inefficiently high activity level • A rule of strict liability leads to the efficiently level of injurer activity, but an inefficiently high level of victim activity

  31. Adding activity levels to our results on precaution… Injurer Precaution Victim Precaution Injurer Activity Victim Activity No Liability Zero Efficient Too High Efficient Strict Liability Efficient Zero Efficient Too High Simple Negligence Efficient Efficient Negligence with a Defense of Contributory Negligence Efficient Efficient Comparative Negligence Efficient Efficient Strict Liability with Defense of Contributory Negligence Efficient Efficient

  32. What about activity levels under negligence rules? • Simple negligence: injurer is only liable if he was negligent • Leads injurer to take efficient precaution, so injurer expects to not be liable for any accidents that do occur • So injurer ignores cost of accidents when deciding on activity level (how much to drive) • Injurer drives carefully, but still drives too much • Victim bears “residual risk” • Victim bikes carefully, and bikes efficient amount

  33. Adding activity levels to our results on precaution… Injurer Precaution Victim Precaution Injurer Activity Victim Activity No Liability Zero Efficient Too High Efficient Strict Liability Efficient Zero Efficient Too High Simple Negligence Efficient Efficient Too High Efficient Negligence with a Defense of Contributory Negligence Efficient Efficient Comparative Negligence Efficient Efficient Strict Liability with Defense of Contributory Negligence Efficient Efficient

  34. Negligence with Defense of Contributory Negligence, and Comparative Negligence • Either rule: efficient precaution by both parties • Either rule: if neither party was negligent, injurer does not owe damages • So victim is residual risk bearer (pays for accidents) • So victim weighs cost of accidents against benefits of activity, takes efficient activity level • Injurer ignores cost of accidents, takes inefficiently high activity level

  35. Adding activity levels to our results on precaution… Injurer Precaution Victim Precaution Injurer Activity Victim Activity No Liability Zero Efficient Too High Efficient Strict Liability Efficient Zero Efficient Too High Simple Negligence Efficient Efficient Too High Efficient Negligence with a Defense of Contributory Negligence Efficient Efficient Too High Efficient Comparative Negligence Efficient Efficient Too High Efficient Strict Liability with Defense of Contributory Negligence Efficient Efficient

  36. Strict Liability with Defense of Contributory Negligence • If victim is not negligent, injurer is liable • Leads to efficient precaution by both, so injurer is liable • Injurer is residual risk bearer • Injurer weighs cost of accidents against benefits of activity, takes efficient activity level • Victim ignores cost of accidents, takes inefficient high activity level

  37. Adding activity levels to our results on precaution… Injurer Precaution Victim Precaution Injurer Activity Victim Activity No Liability Zero Efficient Too High Efficient Strict Liability Efficient Zero Efficient Too High Simple Negligence Efficient Efficient Too High Efficient Negligence with a Defense of Contributory Negligence Efficient Efficient Too High Efficient Comparative Negligence Efficient Efficient Too High Efficient Strict Liability with Defense of Contributory Negligence Efficient Efficient Efficient Too High

  38. Adding activity levels to our results on precaution… take precaution only to AVOID liability precaution is efficient, butactivity level is too high Injurer Precaution Victim Precaution Injurer Activity Victim Activity No Liability Zero Efficient Too High Efficient Strict Liability Efficient Zero Efficient Too High Simple Negligence Efficient Efficient Too High Efficient Negligence with a Defense of Contributory Negligence Efficient Efficient Too High Efficient Comparative Negligence Efficient Efficient Too High Efficient Strict Liability with Defense of Contributory Negligence Efficient Efficient Efficient Too High

  39. Adding activity levels to our results on precaution… precaution and activity levelare both efficient to reduce accidents, since he bears their cost Injurer Precaution Victim Precaution Injurer Activity Victim Activity No Liability Zero Efficient Too High Efficient Strict Liability Efficient Zero Efficient Too High Simple Negligence Efficient Efficient Too High Efficient Negligence with a Defense of Contributory Negligence Efficient Efficient Too High Efficient Comparative Negligence Efficient Efficient Too High Efficient Strict Liability with Defense of Contributory Negligence Efficient Efficient Efficient Too High

  40. With each negligence rule… • One party can avoid liability by taking efficient precaution • Leads to efficient precaution • But inefficient activity level • Other party is the residual risk bearer – even when he takes precaution, he is still liable • Leads to efficient precaution • And also efficient activity level • Who should bear residual risk? • One way to answer is to ask whose activity level has greater impact on efficiency

  41. So which rule is best? • “Put the incentive where it does the most good” • Efficient rule depends on which choices have greatest impact • If only injurer’s choices (precaution + activity) matter  strict liability is better rule • If bilateral precaution  negligence • Which negligence rule – depends whose activity level is more important • Friedman (citing Posner): this is why very dangerous activities often covered by strict liability • Blasting with dynamite, keeping a lion as a pet • Even with proper precaution, still very dangerous, so injurer activity level is important

  42. Friedman: activity is just unobservable precaution • Activity is just another type of precaution, but type where court can’t determine efficient level • Court can tell inefficient for me to drive at night with headlights off • Can’t tell how many miles it’s efficient for me to drive • Determination of negligence can only be based on observable precaution, not unobservable • Negligence rule leads to efficient levels of observable precaution by both parties • Simple negligence leads only to efficient observable precaution by injurer, but efficient precaution by victim as well • Strict liability leads to efficient observable and unobservable precaution by injurer, but no precaution by victim

  43. Shavell’s Take(we won’t get to this Monday)

  44. Steven Shavell, Strict Liability Versus Negligence • Focuses on injurer precaution and activity • Compares strict liability to negligence rules • Accidents between strangers (what we’ve been doing): • “Under a negligence rule, all that an injurer has to do to avoid the possibility of liability is to make sure to exercise due care if he engages in his activity. • Consequently he will not be motivated to consider the effect on accident losses of his choice of whether to engage in his activity or, more generally, of the level at which to engage in his activity; he will choose his level of activity in accordance only with the personal benefits so derived. • But surely an increase in his level of activity will typically raise expected accident losses. Thus he will be led to choose too high a level of activity.”

  45. Steven Shavell, Strict Liability Versus Negligence • Whereas under strictly liability… • “Because an injurer must pay for losses whenever he in involved in an accident, he will be induced to consider the effect on accident losses of both his level of care and his level of activity. • His decisions will therefore be efficient. • Because drivers will be liable for losses sustained by pedestrians, they will decide not only to exercise due care in driving but also to drive only when the utility gained from it outweights expected liability payments to pedestrians.” • (This is exactly what we had already concluded…)

  46. Steven Shavell, Strict Liability Versus Negligence InjurerPrecaution InjurerActivity ACCIDENTS BETWEEN STRANGERS Simple Negligence Efficient Too High Strict Liability Efficient Efficient

  47. Next case: accidents between “sellers and strangers” • Injurer is in a competitive business, but not with victim • victim is not injurer’s customer, but a stranger • Example: taxi drivers • provide service to their passengers • risk hitting other pedestrians • Shavell assumes perfect competition • Price = marginal cost of “production” • Sales = number of passengers who demand rides at that price

  48. Accidents between businesses and strangers • Strict liability • Taxi drivers pay for accidents, set x = x* to minimize costs • Perfect competition  cost of remaining accidents is built into price • Taxi passengers face price that includes cost of accidents • Passengers internalize risk of accidents, demand efficient number of rides • Negligence rule • Taxi drivers still take efficient precaution, to avoid liability • But since drivers don’t bear residual risk, cost of accidents not built into price • Passengers face prices that are too low • Demand for taxi rides inefficiently high

  49. Steven Shavell, Strict Liability Versus Negligence InjurerPrecaution InjurerActivity ACCIDENTS BETWEEN STRANGERS Simple Negligence Efficient Too High Strict Liability Efficient Efficient ACCIDENTS BETWEEN BUSINESSES AND STRANGERS Simple Negligence Efficient Too High Strict Liability Efficient Efficient

  50. Final case: accidents between businesses and their own customers • Example: restaurants taking precaution to reduce risk of food poisoning • How accurately do customers perceive risks? • 1. Customers can accurately judge risk of each restaurant • 2. Customers can accurately judge average level of risk, but not differences across restaurants • 3. Customers ignorant of risks

More Related