590 likes | 976 Views
Great investors and hedge fund managers: their methods and evaluation. Prof William T Ziemba Alumni Professor of Financial Modeling and Stochastic Optimization (Emeritus) Mathematical Institute, Oxford University ICMA Centre, University of Reading
E N D
Great investors and hedge fund managers: their methods and evaluation Prof William T Ziemba Alumni Professor of Financial Modeling and Stochastic Optimization (Emeritus) Mathematical Institute, Oxford University ICMA Centre, University of Reading William T Ziemba Investment Management Inc, Vancouver, BC Dr Z Investments Inc, San Luis Obispo, CA and Private International Wealth Management, BC Capital Group, Nassau CARISMA Seminar, June 25, 2007 Session 3: Anomalies, security market imperfections and behavioral biases 11. The various efficient/inefficient market camps: why Buffett wants to endow university chairs in efficient market theory. WTZIMI
The Camps: Can you beat the stock market? • Efficient Markets (E): • current prices are fair and correct except possibly for transactions costs • commissions, bid-ask spread, price pressures - for small caps the latter can be large • 4.6% on average for a $50,000 sale according to a Barra study • Fama et al, 1960s to 80s • Sharpe index funds - they still beat about 75% of active managers • DFA - manage > $25 billion passive funds • Risk Premium (RP): • markets are basically efficient but one can realize extra return by bearing additional risk • if returns are above average, then the risk must be there somewhere; you cannot get higher returns without bearing additional risk • for example, beating the market index S&P500 is possible but not risk adjusted by the CAPM • Beta must then be greater than one (Fama et al 1990s, Frank Russell, DFA) WTZIMI
Camps (cont’d) • Genius (C) • superior investors exist who are brilliant or geniuses but you cannot determine in advance who they are: the Samuelson argument • you can determine them ex ante and to some extent they have persistent superior performance, Soros did this with futures with superior picking of futures to bet on; traders are “made not born” philosophy • Efficient markets is hogwash (D) • by evaluating companies and buying them when their value is more than their price, you can easily beat the market by taking a long term view • find these stocks and hold them forever • find a few such stocks that you understand well • forget about diversification,only buy winners, use some of your money to endow chairs in the efficient market hypothesis. Buffett et al, • bet on insurance etc when the odds are greatly in your favor WTZIMI
Camps (cont’d) • Markets are beatable (A) • through behavioral biases, security market anomalies using computerized superior betting procedures • construct risk arbitrage situations with positive expectation • research the strategy well and follow it for long periods of time repeating the advantage many times • factor models are useful and show that beta is not one of the most important variables to predict stock prices • very focused,disciplined, well researched strategies with superior execution and risk control • focus on not losing • they rarely have blowouts: Thorp, Benter, Blair Hull, Harry McPike, James Simons (Renaissance Hedge Fund), David Swensen (Yale Endowment) • blowouts occur more in hedge funds that do not focus on not losing and true diversification and over-bet; when a bad scenario hits them,they get wiped out: LTCM WTZIMI
How do investors and consultants do in all these cases? • All can be multimillionaires but the centimillionaires are in (C), (D) and (A) (like the six listed with the exception of Swensen) • WTZ was fortunate to work/consult with four of these and was also the main consultant to the Frank Russell Research Department for nine years • (A) people earn money by winning and taking a percent of the profits, Thorp returned 15.8% net with $200 million under management; fees $8 million/year • (E) and (RP) people earn money from fees by collecting assets through superior marketing and sticky investment decisions WTZIMI
Fundamental anomalies: Jacobs and Levy (US model), Ziemba (Japan model), use in long/short strategies • Fundamental Factors in U.S. and Japanese Stock Returns • Schwartz and Ziemba (2000) Predicting returns on the Tokyo stock exchange • No quantitative strategy including mispricings will work all the time;the aim is to use strategies that add value on average over time • Model developed for Yamaichi Research in Tokyo in 1989 • Similar model used by Buchanan Partners, a London hedge fund • Idea: use many factors to predict the best stocks and the worst stocks • Ranking 1, ..., N. • Then use this in various types of trading and investing • especially long cheap warrants, short bad stocks • Shorting cost 4%/year for many stocks. • For references see Ziemba and Ziemba (2007) WTZIMI
Which Factors are the Most Important on the NYSE? • Jacobs/Levy study (1988a,b) • They turned this into a multibillion dollar investment company in Philadelphia • First paper to use factor model to separate out best from worst stocks • 25 factors • 1500 largest capitalized stocks • monthly revisions of most variables, Jan 1978 to Dec 1986 • normalized factors • excess return vs factor exposure • cumulative effects relative to benchmark (S&P500) • univariate naive effects • multivariate pure effects WTZIMI
Equity attributes WTZIMI
Low PE Small size WTZIMI
Beta was not a particularly good variable once other variables are considered WTZIMI
Monthly average returns to anomalies, January vs non-January WTZIMI
But if you start in 1926 then large caps beat small caps which never catch up after the 1929 crash WTZIMI
Typical Value Line/S&P500 spread for cash and futures for the 1997-1998 turn of the year See Rendon-Ziemba (2007) for plots like this for the Value Line/S&P spread and Russell 2000/S&P spread for 1982-2005 WTZIMI
Small cap minus large cap returns for December 1926-1997 (Noise) WTZIMI
Small cap minus large cap returns for January 1926-1998 WTZIMI
Some conclusions • Strong variables are • Low PE • Small size • sales/price • Trend in earnings estimates lagged 1, 2, 3 months • current earnings surprise • earnings torpedo • relative strength • residual reversal lagged 1 or 2 months • In January also • yield • short and long term tax • low price • book/price • neglect WTZIMI
Conclusions (cont’d) • Jacobs-Levy manage about $20 billion using these and other ideas • WTZ long term student/trader in January effect, major change in 1990s especially 1996-8; so called January effect exists but only for short time in December and mostly in futures markets, so January results are probably unreliable?? • See Rendon-Ziemba (2007) for update on January effect in futures markets WTZIMI
Which factors were the most important on the Tokyo stock exchange up to 1989 and in the early 1990s? • Ziemba study at Yamaichi Research Institute, Tokyo • Data • June 1979 to September 1989 (some tests to 1969) • All, 1163, stocks on first section of TSE • Returns • Cumulative effect relative to TOPIX • Univariate naive effects • Multivariate pure effects • Rotate stocks month by month • Normalized effects of 30 factors • Research completed in fall 1989 • Published in Ziemba-Schwartz (1991) Invest Japan, Probus and Schwartz and Ziemba (2000) • Did Yamaichi use?? • Buchanan hedge fund in London used similar model 1991-1998 for hedge warrant arbitrage portfolios with good success WTZIMI
Definition of Fundamental and Technical Variables D=difference, A=acceleration, P=price BV=book value, Div= dividend WTZIMI
Variables (cont’d) WTZIMI
Future earnings growth (average of 3 forecasting services) over price is the best variable WTZIMI
Arbitrage: A typical Thorpian risk arbitrage trade: buy A for a low price, sell A’ for a high price: wait for them to converge, application to Nikkei puts 1989-90 One of the most important theoretical ideas in the theory of finance. Generally finance theories assume no arbitrage. Buy for A, sell for B where B>A at the same time: cannot lose Risk Arbitrage Buy for A at time t, sell for B where B>A at time >t: could lose Arbitrage exists but is rare Prediction markets through betting exchanges show some current examples of arbitrage and risk arbitrage WTZIMI
Two such examples are: B Construct the arbitrage with a sequence of investments the net result yields the arbitrage B Find mispricings in different localities that yield the arbitrage - today’s betting exchanges are like this. WTZIMI
Locks at the Racetrack: Constructing an arbitrage; similar analysis applies to the stock market • Track take (transactions costs) are • % of betting pool • Rounding down to nearest 10 or 20¢ Payoff per dollar bet on i for an ijk finish (in any order) is Minimum payoff 2.10 or 2.20 per $2 bet to win, place and show Suppose there is a super horse, then if one bets a lot on that horse and a little bit on all the other horses, then one can construct a lock or arbitrage: you cannot lose WTZIMI
Alabama Stakes, Saratoga, August 11. 1979 The public’s win odds and show bets. The conversion of win odds to win probabilities accounts for the public’s biases, see reading 15. Scenario 1: If DD is in the money, all 3 horses pay off $1.05/$ bet; this is more than we lost on the other two horses. Scenario 2: If DD is out of the money, then we want bets so that then we do not lose money. WTZIMI
Strategy: make same profit regardless of the finish We bet x on the favorite k = fraction of S pool on favorite by the crowd (1-k)/(n-1) = fraction of S pool on all the other n-1 horses by the crowd We bet an equal amount y on all the other horses. Our total wager = x+(n-1)y S1: If favorite is in $, we collect 5% on x and 2 of the y bets but lose (n-3)y on the (n–3) losers S2: If favorite is out of the $, assume so far our bets do not influence the odds (prices) loss on the other n-4 losses loss on the favorite profit on the 3 horses in the money WTZIMI
How it works To guarantee a particular payout regardless of the finish This yields a profit of The bets are actually not quite equal and the bets may influence the odds DD had k= .955 Bet is $2364 on DD $34 on the other 4 horses WTZIMI
S1: 1 = $53.60 S2: if bets were equal 2 would be $53.60 but the bets were not equal The 2 depends on the finish of the top 3 finishers Average=53.60 WTZIMI
What if the bets are different? x= bet on DD y1= bet on Its in the Air y2= bet on Mairzy Doates y3= bet on Poppycock y4= bet on Croquis R=guaranteed return Use a linear program WTZIMI
Discussion • Locks or true arbitrages exist but not very often. • They are exploitable but work is involved. • The gain is about 2% on money invested. • My friends Jackson and Waldron in Dublin found a flaw in the British/Irish betting rules similar to this, published in Economics of Gambling,L Vaughn Williams, ed, 2004 • WTZ spotted it in the 1987 book but they wrote it up and did it to the tune of 50,000 pounds before the rules changed. • Betting exchanges make such arbitrages more likely as there are more readily accessible markets. WTZIMI
Arbitrage Different prices in different places so: 6.44% riskless profit By taking risk you go to risk arbitrage but you usually make more Betfair/Betdaq/Mansion/Matchbook/Tradesports; different prices can be used to construct real arbitrages and risk arbitrages. WTZ papers on this in Hausch, Lo and Ziemba (1994) Efficiency of Racetrack Betting Markets, Academic Press (available from WTZ) WTZIMI
www.betfair.com wtz +0.25 200£ @ 1.12 If I win +24.02£ If I lose -200£ I could cover at 1.07/1.08 and lock in a risk arbitrage WTZIMI
www.betfair.com wtz £200 @ 1.04 so this replaces 1.05 lay £30, so it now reads 1.04 1.05 £200 £30 WTZ £150 @ 1.04 Jan 31, 2006; maybe ?? the last hike? WTZIMI
Risk Arbitrage in Action • A typical convergence trade: the Nikkei put warrant market of 1989-90 • Buy A, Sell A’ cheaper and exit when the prices of A and A’ are within a transaction band • Ed Thorp and I, with assistance from Julian Shaw, did a convergence trade based on differing put warrant prices on the Toronto and American stock exchanges. • The trade was successful and Thorp won the over $1 million risk adjusted hedge fund contest run by Barron's in 1990. • There were risks involved and hedge fund risk management care was needed. What follows is a brief description of the main points. • Additional discussion and technical details appear in Shaw, Thorp and Ziemba (1995). • Japanese stock and land prices were astronomical and very intertwined, see Stone and Ziemba (1993) for more on this. WTZIMI
The historical development leading up to the NSA put warrants, 1989 • Tsukamoto Sozan Building in Ginza 2-Chome in central Tokyo is the most expensive land in the country with one square meter priced at ¥37.7 million or about $279,000 U.S. at the (December 1990) exchange rate of about ¥135 per U.S. dollar. • Downtown Tokyo land values highest in the world, about $800 million an acre • Office rents in Tokyo are twice those in London yet land costs 40 times as much • Japanese stock market up 221 times in yen and 553 in dollars as measured by the Nikkei stock average from 1949 to end of 1989. • Despite this huge rise, there had been twenty declines from 1949 to 1989 of 10% or more. Plus two more in 1990 and two more in 1991. So the market was volatile. Also both stocks and bonds were highly levered with debt. • There was a tremendous feeling in the West that the Japanese stock market was overpriced as was the land market. For example, the Emperor's palace was reputed to be worth all of California or Canada. It took me 15-20 minutes to walk across it. • Japanese land was about 23% of world's non-human capital. Japanese PE ratios were 60+. WTZIMI
Historical development (cont’d) • Various studies were made by academics and brokerage researchers to argue that the high prices of stocks and land were justified by higher long run growth rates and lower interest rates in Japan versus the US. See for example, Ziemba and Schwartz (1991) and French and Poterba (1991). • However, similar models predicted a large fall in prices once interest rates rose from late 1998 to August 1990. • Hence both must crash! • There was a tremendous feeling in Japan that their economy and products were the best in the world. • There was a natural trade in 1989, early 1990 • Westerners bet Japanese market will fall • Japanese bet Japanese market will not fall WTZIMI
NSA puts and calls on the Toronto and American stock exchanges, 1989-1992 • Various Nikkei put warrants which were three year American options were offered to the market to fill the demand by speculators who wanted to bet that the NSA would fall. • The various NSA puts and calls were of three basic types. Let NSA0 be today's NSA and E0 be today's exchange rate. Then Ee is the strike price and NSAe be the exchange rate on expiry for Canadian or US dollars into yen. The symbol (X)+ means the greater of X or zero. • Our convergence trades in late 1989 to early 1990 involved: • selling expensive Canadian currency Bankers Trust I's and II's and buying cheaper US currency BT's on the American Stock Exchange; and • selling expensive Kingdom of Denmark and Saloman I puts on the ASE and buying the same BT I's also on the ASE both in US dollars. • This convergence trade was especially interesting because the price discrepancy was based mainly on the unit size (0.5 vs 0.2 of an NSA) WTZIMI
Relative values of the put warrants • We performed a complex pricing of all the warrants which is useful in the optimization of the positions size, see Shaw, Thorp and Ziemba (1995). • The table gives insight into this in a simple way. • For example, 9.8% premium year year means that if you buy the option, the NSA must fall 9.8% each year to break even. • So selling at 9.8% and buying 2.6% looks like a good trade. • A stochastic programming optimization model helps in determining how much to sell give the risks and your wealth level. WTZIMI
Some of the reasons for the different prices were: • Large price discrepancy across Canadian/U.S. border • Canadians trade in Canada, US's trade in U.S • Different credit risk • Different currency risk • Difficulties with borrowing for short sales • Blind emotions vs reality • An inability of speculators to properly price the warrants • The market was confused; % unit became important, BT U.S. cheapest even though its nominal price was highest. WTZIMI
Simulation • A simulation in Shaw, Thorp and Ziemba (1995) showed that for similar parameter values, I's were worth more than II's, which were worth more than III's. • But many investors preferred the currency protected aspect of the II's and overpaid (relative to hedging that risk separately in the currency futures markets) for them relative to the I's. • Look at figures of the two convergence trades. • Relative Cost = (Actual Cost - Theoretical Cost)/Theoretical Cost when s=20% is plotted rather than implied volatility since the latter did not exist when there were deep in the money options trading for less than intrinsic as in this market. • Fair value at 20% NSA volatility and 10% exchange rate volatility is zero on the graph. At one, the puts are trading for double their fair price. • At the peak, the puts were selling for more than three times their fair price. WTZIMI
Risks • The BT-I's did not trade until January 1990 and in about a month the Canadian BT-I's and BT-II's collapsed to fair value and then the trade was unwound. • To hedge before January 1990 one needed to buy an over the counter put from a brokerage firm such as Salomon who made a market in these puts. • The NSA decline in 1990 is also shown on the graph. • Additional risks of such trades is being bought in and shorting the puts too soon and having the market price of them go higher. • We had only minor problems with these risks. WTZIMI
Size Effect • For the second trade, the price discrepancy lasted about a month. • The market prices were about $18 and $9 where they theoretically should have had a 5 to 2 ratio since one put was worth 20% and the other 50% of an NSA and trade at $20 and $8. • These puts were not identical so this is risk arbitrage not arbitrage. • The discrepancy here is similar to the small firm, low price effect (see Keim and Ziemba, 2000). WTZIMI