1 / 26

Inferences from Litigated Cases

Inferences from Litigated Cases. Dan Klerman & Yoon-Ho Alex Lee Law and Economic Theory Conference December 7, 2013. MOTIVATING QUESTION. Take an area of private law .

nibaw
Download Presentation

Inferences from Litigated Cases

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Inferences from Litigated Cases Dan Klerman & Yoon-Ho Alex Lee Law and Economic Theory Conference December 7, 2013

  2. MOTIVATING QUESTION • Take an area of private law. • Suppose in State A, the legal standard governing liability is f. In State B, the standard is g, more plaintiff-friendly.What should we expect to observe in terms of the rate of plaintiff’s trial victory among litigated cases, all else equal? • Alternatively, suppose we observe a higher rate of plaintiff’s trial victory among litigated cases in State B with g, as compared to State A, with f. Can we validly make an inference that g is more plaintiff-friendly than f, all else equal?

  3. Theoretical Literature on Settlement and Litigation “50%!” “Any deviation from 50% is from noise/errors or asymmetric stakes!” - Priest & Klein (1984) “No inferences regarding the legal standard are possible!” - Wittman (1985)(interpreting Priest & Klein) “Any frequency of plaintiff win is possible!” - Shavell (1996)

  4. Standard Models of Settlement and Litigation • Divergent Expectations (Priest & Klein (1984)) • Asymmetric Information • Screening (P’ng (1983), Bebchuk (1984), Shavell (1996)) • Defendant has informational advantage • Plaintiff has informational advantage • Signaling (Reinganum & Wilde (1986)) • Defendant has informational advantage • Plaintiff has informational advantage OUR AIM: Across all standard classes of models of settlement/ litigation, valid inferences are possible under plausible assumptions about the distributions of disputes.

  5. Theoretical Literature on Settlement and Litigation “50%!” “Any deviation from 50% is from noise/errors or asymmetric stakes!” - Priest & Klein (1984) “No inferences regarding the legal standard are possible!” - Wittman (1985)(interpreting Priest & Klein) “Any frequency of plaintiff win is possible!” - Shavell (1996)

  6. Asymmetric Information:The Screening Model

  7. Screening Model (Bebchuk, Shavell): Overview D has private info, p makes a “take-it-or-leave-it” offer • A legal standard is, f(p), a PDF over [0,1], distributing potential Ds in terms of type p = p’s probability of win. High p for low-quality D. • Damage = d, respective cost of litigating: CD,Cp> 0. • D’s p private info, p makes a “take-or-leave” settlement offer at x. • D’s strategy: Accept if x < pd + CD, reject otherwise. • p offers x to maximize expected recovery: p’s payoff from Litigating Ds p’s payoff from Settling Ds

  8. Screening Model (Bebchuk, Shavell): Overview D has private info, p makes a “take-it-or-leave-it” offer • A legal standard is, f(p), a PDF over [0,1], distributing potential Ds in terms of type p = p’s probability of win. High p for low-quality D. • Liability = d, respective cost of litigating: CD,Cp> 0. • D’s p private info, p makes a “take-or-leave” settlement offer at x. • D’s strategy: Accept if x < pd + CD, reject otherwise. • p offers x to maximize expected recovery: “Any frequency of p win is possible!” – Shavell (1996) Translated: “Give me any probability, and I can construct a PDF producing that probability as p’s win rate.” Empirical Relevance?: We can’t choose the PDF. Relevant Question: Given a PDF representing a legal standard, what condition must a new PDF satisfy in relation to the original PDF to permit valid natural inferences? p’s payoff from Litigating Ds p’s payoff from Settling Ds

  9. Screening Model (Bebchuk, Shavell): Overview D has private info, p makes a “take-it-or-leave-it” offer • How should we understand the “more pro-p” standard? • Given 2 PDFs, f(p) and g(p), what relation describes “more pro-p”? • Stochastic Dominance: not sufficient • Monotone Likelihood Ratio Property: sufficient

  10. Screening Model (Bebchuk, Shavell): Overview D has private info, p makes a “take-it-or-leave-it” offer Exp. Payoff: • FOC over x: • Let , k = : . Hazard rate of fhf(p) Threshold D type

  11. Screening Model (Bebchuk, Shavell): Overview D has private info, p makes a “take-it-or-leave-it” offer • As long as hg(p) < hf(p), under f(p) < under f(p) • But if MLRP (), we have hg(p) < hf(p).

  12. Screening Model (Bebchuk, Shavell): Overview D has private info, p makes a “take-it-or-leave-it” offer • So MLRP implies under f(p) < under g(p), with which we can show p’s win-rate is higher under g(p).

  13. Screening Model (Bebchuk, Shavell): Overview D has private info, p makes a “take-it-or-leave-it” offer Proposition 1 (Inferences Under the Screening Model). When p is screening, the probability that pwill prevail in litigated cases is strictly higher under a “more pro-plaintiff” legal standard, as characterized by monotone likelihood ratio property. Proposition 1A (Inferences Under the Screening Model). Same result when D is screening. PDF Families over [0,1] Exhibiting MLRP: Over [0,1]: uniform, beta, rising triangle, falling triangle Truncated: normal, exponential, binomial, Poisson

  14. Asymmetric Information:The Signaling Model

  15. Signaling Model (Reinganum & Wilde): Overview p has private info, p makes a “take-it-or-leave-it” offer • p knows type. Type is probability that plaintiff will prevail at trial • p makes a “take-it-or-leave-it” offer, s(p), that increases with type • D rejects offer with probability, p(s), that increases with the offer and is largely independent of the distribution of disputes • So high probability plaintiffs are disproportionately represented among litigated cases • Pro-plaintiff shift in law • increases proportion of high probability plaintiffs in population (e.g. in pool of litigated + settled cases) • increases proportion of high probability plaintiffs in litigated subset • increases observed probability of plaintiff success

  16. Signaling Model (Reinganum & Wilde): Overview p has private info, p makes a “take-it-or-leave-it” offer Proposition 2 (Inferences Under the Signaling Model). When p has the informational advantage, the probability that pwill prevail in litigated cases is strictly higher under a more pro-plaintiff legal standard, as characterized by monotone likelihood ratio property. Proposition 2A (Inferences Under the Signaling Model). Same result when D has the informational advantage.

  17. The Priest-Klein Model

  18. Priest-Klein Model: Overview DISTRIBUTION OF ALL DISPUTES (SETTLED OR LITIGATED) p WINS (BLUE) p WINS (BLUE) DEGREE OF D FAULT DEGREE OF D FAULT Distributions of litigated disputes if parties make moderate errors Distributions of litigated disputes if parties make small errors PRO-D STANDARD PRO-p STANDARD

  19. Priest-Klein Model: Overview Proposition 3 (Inferences Under the Priest-Klein Model). Under the Priest-Klein model, if the distribution of disputes has a log concave CDF, then p’s win-rate among litigated cases increasesas the decision standard becomes more pro-p. PDFs with Log-Concave CDFs: normal, generalized normal, skew normal, exponential, logistic, Laplace, chi, beta, gamma, log-normal, Weibull…

  20. Priest-Klein Model • As legal standard becomes morepro-D, p’s win-rate decreases • Effect varies with standard deviation of prediction error • Paper presents evidence that standard deviation is large

  21. Why We Disagree with P&K I • Priest & Klein understood that plaintiff trial win rates would vary with the legal standard unless prediction errors were very small (e.g. σ=0.1) • They estimated prediction errors from trial rates based on simulations • Lower prediction errors produce lower trial rates • Exact effect depends on (C-S)/J = (cost of trial – cost of settlement)/judgment • If (C-S)/J = 0.33, then 2% trial rate implies very small prediction errors (σ=0.1) • If (C-S)/J ≥ 0.66, then 2% trial rate implies prediction errors large enough to make plaintiff trial win rates vary significantly with legal standard

  22. Why We Disagree with P&K II • Priest & Klein assumed (C-S)/J=0.33, because 33% is standard contingent fee percentage • That is wrong for two reasons • 1) (C-S)/J = (Cπ-S π)/J + (CΔ-SΔ)/J • So, at best, contingent fee measures (Cπ-S π)/J • (C-S)/J ≈ 2 (Cπ-S π)/J = 0.66 • 2) Under simple contingent fee, lawyer gets paid same percentage whether case settles or goes to trial • C/J = S/J which implies (C-S)/J = 0 • Can’t estimate (C-S)/J from contingent fee • RAND (1986) estimates (C-S)/J = 0.75

  23. Extensions • Effect of different decisionmakers • Republican versus Democratic judges • Male versus female judges • 6 or 12 person jury • Whether factor affects trial outcome • Race or gender of plaintiff • In-state or out-of-state defendant • Law firm quality • Effect of change in composition of cases • Business cycle induces stronger or weaker plaintiffs to sue (Siegelman & Donohue 1995)

  24. Caveats • Assumes that distribution of underlying behavior doesn’t change • Not usually true • Exceptions • Retroactive legal change • Uninformed defendants • Analysis of judicial biases or case factors, when cases randomly assigned • Advice to empiricists • Worry less about settlement selection • Worry more about changes in behavior • Distribution of disputes (litigated & settled) • Monotone likelihood ratio property for asymmetric information • Logconcave for Priest-Klein

  25. Conclusions • Selection effects are real • But, under all standard settlement models, change in legal standard, under plausible assumptions, will lead to predictable changes in plaintiff trial win rate • Bebchuk screening model • Reinganum-Wilde signaling model • Priest-Klein divergent expectations model • Pro-plaintiff change in law will lead to increase in plaintiff trial win rate • So may be able to draw valid inferences from litigated cases • Measure legal change • Measure biases of decision makers • Identify factors affecting outcomes • Good news for empiricists

More Related